Tuesday, January 17th 2012
A talk and presentation by Professor
Lindsay Falvey FTSE, Former Dean of Land and Food, and Chair
of Agriculture, University of Melbourne, Australia; Fellow/Life Member,
Clare Hall, University of Cambridge, UK
This talk introduces a book of the above title,
free copies of which were provided to most of the INTG audience.
By way of introduction, a short description of
a brief period in ancient Rome illustrates what happens when we forget
that food comes first – in politics as in survival. Much in Roman
history can sound familiar today. Cicero’s observation of civic
decline mentions poor fiscal management, indigence and abuse of
government positions. But it was farming that he considered the best of
occupations, which he defended at law as being a ‘teacher of
economy, industry and justice’. Likewise, food production was
written about from Cato’s ‘De Agricultura’ to
Columella’s ‘Res Rustica’ to Pliny
the Elder’s ‘Naturalis Historia’. In
fact, Pliny the Elder’s precursor of all modern encyclopedias was
sponsored by a dynasty that had learned the centrality of food security
for Rome – Vespasian’s Flavian Dynasty.
We owe this knowledge about food and Rome to
Pliny’ nephew, Pliny the Younger, who in the year 100 in a fit of
rhetoric claimed that Rome was self-sufficient in grain and did not
need to import from Egypt. Yet in his lifetime, food scarcity had been
used as the lever for a coup d’état. During the 60s,
Rome’s vast grain network in North Africa was of no value as
mismanagement and conflict interrupted shipping. The great Empire had
neglected its own food security in the latter period of Nero’s
reign and the ensuing years of revolving Emperors and civil wars.
It took a capable leader to reestablish the
essential security of the Empire by first of all securing its food
supply. Vespasian’s led by possibly withholding food to focus
military attention, and then took control and secured food supply. The
he set about repealing unfair laws, reintegrating Greek provinces,
rewarding honesty, supporting natural philosophers and constructing the
Rome we think of today – the its Coliseum and so forth. With
workable administrative systems, sound organization, minimal corruption
and the rule of law, he maintained respect by his own simplicity of
lifestyle, in contrast to the debating senators who styled themselves
as philosophers.
This Flavian dynasty was carried on by his
sons and saw a ceasing of religious persecution and rejection of
expansionist warfare. Good governance produced the most economically
secure period of the Empire. Nepotism was punished and unworthy
senators expelled. And so, while popular with the people and the army,
his son Domitian was despised by the Senate for abandoning the
traditional façade of Senatorial democracy. And so eventually he
was assassinated. Senator Pliny the Younger was still around and he
joined fellow Senators to expunge Domitian’s public memory by
writing damning histories of him as a tyrant.
But Domitian’s successor was his close
confidant who retained the established structure of good governance for
a long-lasting dynasty, with food supply so secure that Pliny could
naively argue that Rome was so great she no longer needed Egypt’s
grain.
It is the same today. The roles of Vespasian
managing food first and Pliny’s ignorance are today filled by
concerned governments of food insecure countries on the one hand, and
insulated rich and food secure countries on the other.
Today wealthy countries assume food supply is
secure. But ask the urban poor in less developed cities of food-deficit
countries and you quickly learn that urban starvation occurred in a
2007-8 crisis of failed grain crops. The fact that it hardly featured
in rich nations’ media reflects a distance from reality that is
now palpable. That wealthy countries have since been preoccupied by
their financial crisis is hardly an excuse. Just as parochial Roman
senators misconceived their food supply, so rich countries today
blithely bask in ignorance of world food realities.
I have used this potted, and biased, history
to illustrate how Pliny’s fatuous claim of food security
independent of agricultural reality is much the same as that of
today’s policy makers who claim that free and open trade in food
will solve food shortages. And just as arguing against the Senator was
heretical, so the view I present here may be so seen. For the view that
I espouse, and as detailed in the book, is that rather than follow the
usual UN and aid approaches that mix food security with other
development issues, it is absolutely critical that food security
for survival be the focus and that food’s main producers, small
farmers, be the target.
So let’s look at views of food today. The
philosophical underpinnings of debates about food may be grouped into
three arguments:
1) food viewed as a commodity, and hence tradable like any other good;
2) food as a product of nature to be balanced with other products
natural ecosystems yielding fresh water and biodiversity and
culturally-determined aesthetic values, and
3) food as a human right.
These diverse approaches are brought to the
development table by donors influenced by their own domestic pressures
and responsibilities and so, even with the best of intent, can produce
only biased statements of food security. For example, that of FAO,
which by mentioning access to food and nutritional matters, omits
reference to food production. This has allowed re-interpretation by
some donors to orient funds to their domestic interests through such
issues as obesity. It begs the fact that most food is produced and
consumed in Asia.
Here in Asia where more than half of the world
lives, more than 90% of world rice, 40% of cereals and 40% of meat are
produced and are mainly consumed in the country of production. After 30
years of economic growth and significant reductions in poverty, Asia
still contains more than half of the world’s poor in the monetary
terms that agencies use to define ‘poor’, mainly in rural
areas. Such facts are usually used to justify general agricultural
development to also meet the objective of poverty reduction. Relative
success in this approach has led to food security being subordinated to
a combination of agricultural and rural development supported by trade
of cheap food. This only works in countries with one or both of a food
surplus or valuable goods to trade; and even in the second case, the
ability to purchase food relies on food being available. Middle Eastern
countries were more than surprised in 2007-8 when they learned this
lesson – this is why they have returned to the Joseph-like
conservative food governance, production and storage policies of
Genesis.

The difference I am talking about between current
aid approaches and how things really work is illustrated by the
crossed-out dotted lines in the figure. Aid usually assumes that
agricultural and rural development can directly produce development and
poverty alleviation. The way it actually works is that food security
underpins national stability, which with good governance can produce
development and poverty alleviation.
Globally, food security is said to exist for some
4.7 billion persons with another two billion being food insecure in
terms of sub-standard diets that impair physical and intellectual
capacity. If global population stabilizes at nine billion around 2050
as optimistically predicted, food demand will probably rise to an
equivalent of 12 billion of today’s persons due to such factors
as affluence-induced food preferences and food wastage in urban supply
chains. Unless food security is realistically defined as basic food for
survival, it is not achievable without major changes in our worldviews.
The current worldview of ‘donors’
– we who feel secure – is that we allocate the role to
solve food insecurity to aid agencies, and so assuage any feeling of
guilt and take comfort in being insulated from any negative effects
like starvation in foreign parts. But that time has passed. Just as
food was the first principle of security in ancient Rome, so it remains
today in a globalized world. Where starving rural dwellers once quietly
shriveled and died, today’s marginalized in cities riot –
and rapid communication exacerbates the impact leading to such other
events as lawlessness, war and emigration. Such matters then attract
the attention of the ‘insulated’ rich. The diagram tracks
food prices and food related protests and riots (from von Braun, IFPRI
2009) through the recent crisis – a crisis of a significance
exceeding the West’s current preoccupations yet hardly noticed.

Why did food prices (grain is used as a proxy as
it is the major food source in the world) rise? We are used to hearing
of the advances in food production – a sustained miracle of
science. Indeed, wheat prices have declined over the century that
population has trebled because past research generated ever-new
technologies. So did the price of all grain really rise? To answer that
question we must look at the earlier graph to see it did – but
not as much as rice. And rice is predominantly the food of Asia.
In ASEAN, Thailand and Vietnam (outside ASEAN,
India is second to Thailand) sell rice surpluses – Myanmar may to
rejoin this group in coming decades – but the proportion sold is
small compared to that consumed domestically. And this introduces
another forgotten fact: >90 percent of all the world’s food is
consumed domestically, never crossing a national border.
Rice differs from other major cereals. It is
mainly produced by smallholders, and as it is consumed locally, it is
managed nationally as a strategic commodity. It is not traded as openly
as, for example wheat, which means that hoarding, precautionary
purchases or panic buying, and prohibitions on export can
disproportionately affect price – as occurred between November
2007 and May 2008 when rice prices doubled. Some events on the rice
price path are presented in following figure adapted from
Headley’s IFPRI Paper 0889. It seems that drought reduced
India’s wheat production at the same time that export demand for
Indian rice increased, leading India to restrict rice exports.
Interestingly this was the first time such a ban had been imposed and
it led to price escalation as foreign buyers were forced to negotiate
with other suppliers. This in turn raised wider domestic fears and led
to export prohibitions in Vietnam, China, Cambodia, and Egypt, and
panic buying by such food-deficit countries as the Philippines. India
had until that time exported some 20% of world rice, being second only
to Thailand. As a shortage of staple food in a populous country could
be catastrophic, India’s export ban is entirely logical and by
sensible measures would be seen as a sign of good governance. It is
noteworthy that India exempted Bangladesh from the ban, and continued
exports to rich countries of the luxury rice, Basmati.
Yes, it is good governance to feed one’s
people. It allows them to be governable – it is the first
priority in national security. Yet the aid world, caught up in an
ideology derived from non-essential commodities in the Western world
issued statements such as unless [food] trade is kept open and
relative prices are allowed to reflect market scarcity, severe
consequences will emerge. One wonders what implications to take
from such comments! I am not being selective when I use this quotation
– other agencies have similar negative comments.

The disconnection from reality that allows such
policies to be espoused, has at the same time promoted a related
fallacy – that small third-world farmers are an inefficient way
to produce food. The opposite is the truth. Of
the world’s 530 million farms, 85% are less than two hectares and
only 0.6% more than 100 hectares. The small farm sector of poor
countries involves some two billion people – it feeds them and
provides a surplus for non-producers in towns and cities. In round
figures, small farmers feed half of the world, more if we only
considered essential food for basic lifestyles, which would exclude
such luxury foods as out-of-season produce and grain-fed livestock.
Small farmer yields under these intensive conditions are often higher
than under the extensive broadacre systems common in rich countries.
And where research has been oriented to small farms, yield increases
among innovators have exceeded broadacre yield increases.
Why would an aid agency remove small farmers to a
city where transport losses increase his food total demand and to
consolidate his often marginal land into larger holdings that produce
lower yields? The reason seems to be that – excepting
ill-informed mistakes in such policy – most of the actions of
such agencies are based on unchallenged assumptions derived from
Western high-labour-cost situations simply because that is what modern
universities teach to the urbanized elite who gain employment in aid
agencies.
In the book there is a section entitled ‘the
arrogance of ignorance’, which reproduces an haiku by Klausner
quoted in my earlier book on ‘Thai Agriculture’ that
illustrates the separation of the elite urban educated society from the
source of their food:
sitting on top of the rice heap
marveling how distant peasants toil
Thailand in this respect differs little from the
few other major food exporters of the world and should not be counted
as anything but a rich country in the real assets for survival. Its
land is used at levels below capacity, and its public investment in
agricultural technology development is relatively low, simply because
it doesn’t have to produce more; the same applies to such other
large exporters as the USA, Argentina, Australia, Canada and the EU
– and now Brazil. But closer to home, the real lessons come from
populous nations that invest heavily in the sector, led by China.
Other details are presented in the book, including
the need for a sensible balance between broadacre and small farms based
on efficiencies of production of essential food at the lowest overall
cost for the greatest overall food production. It would work against
rural emigration with its high welfare cost. Food supply would be
self-sufficient on most small farms and those with commercial potential
would sell surpluses to provide a higher food output than other
scenarios. This situation would allow a resumption of past trends of
continual reductions in the proportions of persons starving.
The future also includes non-agricultural foods,
which find little market while natural foods are sold cheaply as they
are at present. Unlike some agriculture, these food production
processes suit industrial economies of scale and hence the availability
of such foods would depend on largess from food owners. As these
products can theoretically offer the gift of basic food for reasonably
healthy survival, they must also be factored into any discussion of
future food. But that is a subject for another time.
The message of the book is simple: securing food
for healthy survival – a minimal level of reasonable existence
– should be a central development objective. At present, it
exists as a watered down version of food preferences and is confused by
multiple conflicting objectives. This makes current approaches
unworkable. At the same time, individual countries such as China and
India reject development agency directives and advice when faced with
food shortages, and in so doing act out human behavior that has been
consistent since before civilizations arose and ever since. A
refocusing on food for reasonably healthy survival leads directly to
the main food producers, small farmers, who feed two billion of
themselves and a some of those swelling megacities. In such cities,
food shortages can now inflame riots and anarchy even more than they
have through history. This confirms that basic food security is a first
step towards good governance and socio-economic development. It shocks
some with entrenched views to find that China and India offer lessons
not derivable from the West in terms of the primacy of well-directed
research and policies concerning small farms and survival food
security. Nothing is guaranteed – except insecurity for us all
from emigration to wars – if essential food is not put first in
populous poor countries.
2.3. COMPLEMENT to the MINUTES of the
January 17 meeting (Courtesy of an INTG Correspondent):
2.3.1. A Luang Prabang correspondent (and
hopefully a future speaker) sends this piece of information as food for
thought and as a complement to Lindsay’s talk he could not listen
to. Basically, his text refers to a talk by Andre Drenth on The
Impact of Globalisation and Plant Diseases on Food Security. Andre
Drenth’s informative talk is audible at http://www.apsnet.org/publications/webcasts/Webcasts/ADrenth/player.html
Lindsay’s advice concerning this talk
will be found in § 2.3.2.
At an AIST (Australian Institute of Agricultural
Science and Technology) seminar last November, Andre Drenth (University
of Queensland) gave a talk entitled The Impact of Globalisation
and Plant Diseases on Food Security. This was a fascinating
history of agriculture, input technologies, trade, biosecurity,
pathogens, and the importance of crop protection.
The lessons from the talk are summarised in a
slide which stated:
-
By far the most efficient way to improve production to be able to feed
the world we need to reduce crop losses, currently estimated at 42%.
-
Agricultural production needs to increase 2.3% a year to just meet
global food demand (at present we increase it by 1.5% a year).
-
We are facing the greatest global challenge ever as a discipline.
I asked Andre if I can send the talk to Pestnet
members. Rather than the PDF file which is rather large, and there are
some copyright issues, he has suggested people who are interested in
this subject can go to: http://www.apsnet.org/publications/webcasts/Webcasts/ADrenth/player.html
Andre made a similar presentation on food security and plant pathology
at an APS meeting in the US, and it has been made into a webcast.
It is well worth watching!
grahame
Grahame Jackson - 24 Alt street - Queens
Park - NSW 2022 - Australia
www.pestnet.org - www.ediblearoids.org
- www.terracircle.org.au
2.3.2. Lindsay’s reaction to Andre
Drenth & Grahame Jackson stance:
Fine with me.
Grahame Jackson’s comments from Andre
Drenth’s talk emphasizing the need to reduce crop losses and to
continually increase agricultural production as ‘the greatest
global challenge ever’ are apposite and entirely consistent with
the book that my talk summarized. It highlights that the research need
is constant, and in the terms that I mention in the book, ‘Small
Farmers Secure Food’ (see <http://lindsayfalveysbooks.yolasite.com/small-farmers-secure-food.php>)
needs to be oriented to overriding policies of national food security,
and objective approaches to efficient small farmers.
Best wishes
Lindsay
Prof Lindsay Falvey FTSE
has worked in international agriculture for 40 years, especially in
Thailand. He has led his country’s largest Faculty of Agriculture
as Dean at the University of Melbourne where he was also Chair of
Agriculture, and has advised all major aid and development agencies and
several governments. A Fellow of the Academy of Technological Sciences
& Engineering and a Life Member & Fellow of Clare Hall at the
University of Cambridge, Dr. Falvey has three doctorates (one honorary
from Thailand) all relating to agriculture, as do many of the honors
bestowed on him for his international contributions, including being a
Kitimasuk of the Thai Agricultural Science Society Under the Patronage
of H.M. The King.
|